Carbon Sequestration as Greenhouse Gas Mitigation Policy K.S Kavi Kumar Associate Professor , MSE
Forest ecosystem has potential to capture and retain large volumes of carbon over long periods as trees
absorb carbon through photosynthesis process. A young forest, when growing rapidly, can sequester
relatively large volumes of additional carbon roughly proportional to the forest.s growth in biomass. A
mature forest acts as a reservoir, holding large volumes of carbon even if it is not experiencing net
growth. Forest management can thus have an influence on carbon sequestration. Present estimates
indicate that with appropriate policies the carbon pool in the terrestrial system could increase by up to 100
GtC by the year 2050 compared to the level of carbon that would be sequestered without such policies
(IPCC, 2001). This is equivalent to about 10 to 20% of projected GHG emissions from fossil fuel
consumption during the same period. Reducing deforestation, expanding forest cover, expanding forest
biomass per unit area, and expanding the inventory of long-lived wood products are some of the activities
that could help global community realizing the carbon sequestration potential of forest ecosystem.
Carbon sequestration as a climate change mitigation policy option had received significant attention over
the past several years, and despite widespread opposition to its inclusion in the Kyoto process carbon
sequestration continues to provide handsome competition to other mitigation options. This note provides
a brief overview of economic, legal and institutional issues related to carbon sequestration.
1.0 Economics of Carbon Sequestration
Early works on economics of carbon sequestration focused on examining whether expansion of
forest sinks could play a major role in the effort to slow the accumulation of atmosphere CO These
studies typically used a hypothetical government programs such as subsidies, or government purchases, to
promote forestry management practices like afforestation of agricultural land, or conservation of
forestland, and attempted to estimate cost of sequestration by assessing the costs of various inputs to
production including land, labor and material.
While the general result of these studies suggested that significant opportunities for carbon sequestration
exist all over the world, the specific cost estimates varied substantially across studies from 5 to 500
dollars per ton. Several reasons listed below could be attributed for this wide range of cost estimates.
Type of Model
There are three broad categories of models in literature including engineering, sectoral and econometric
models. The engineering models generally use reported land prices to estimate the social cost of
converting land from one use or practice to another. These models are generally limited in scope to the
immediate on-site effects of a program or practice. On the other hand, sectoral models estimate the
opportunity cost of land using supply and demand equations for each sector under consideration, say
agriculture, forestry, or both (Adams et al., 1999). The costs are derived from estimates of changes in
consumer and producer surplus as the amount of land dedicated to agriculture or forestry expands or
contracts. The models incorporating both agriculture and forestry could include the effects of competing
demands from the two sectors for land. Econometric studies use historic market responses to changes
(generally in timber prices) that are analogous to a government carbon sequestration program to infer how
landowners would respond to direct or indirect carbon prices (Kerr et al 2001; Newell and Stavins 2000).
These models inherently capture the interplay between agriculture and forestlands.
As always the case, the bottom-up models tend to be simple and transparent but fail to include dynamics
of market interactions. The economic sectoral and econometric models on the other hand do capture the
market interactions, but could be data demanding. In general, econometric studies seem to provide
higher estimates of carbon sequestration costs, while the bottom-up models provide lower estimates
because they account for less of the overall counteracting results.
Type of Metric
Various studies in literature differ in terms of the metric used for cost-effectiveness calculations, i. e.,
dollars per ton. The main difference across studies is typically in their definition of the denominator,
namely ton. Three approaches followed in the literature include, ‘flow summation’ approach - wherein
tons are defined as the total flow of carbon throughout the life of the program; ’average storage’ approach
- which defines the tons as the average amount by which storage of carbon in the study area increases;
and ‘levelization/discounting’ approach - is a flow-based metric that discounts the weight of tons more
heavily as they occur further in the future. One way of conceiving this is that the levelization/ discounting
method assumes that the marginal value of sequestering a ton of carbon is constant over time, so that the
present value can be discounted in the same way as any other economic benefit. Among these three
approaches, the ‘flow summation’ approach is conceptually flawed as it leads to an argument that it does
not matter when the carbon is sequestered, and as a result it also does not matter whether it is captured at
all. The ‘average storage’ approach has limited applicability. The ‘levelization/ discounting’ approach on
the other hand has a sound basis and can be applicable for a wide range of programs.
Besides the above discussed two categories studies differ in terms of type of costs they report - i. e.,
point estimates or cost curves based on total, average, or marginal costs. In general, there seems to be an
emerging consensus that cost curves expressing marginal costs as a function of equivalent annualized
sequestration levels are the most useful for comparing across analyses of mitigation options.
Unresolved Issues
There are a few issues that are not fully addressed in the literature and these include:
(a) Secondary benefits from carbon sequestration programs (like, conversion of marginal agricultural land
to forest stands) are believed to be as high as cost of conversion itself, implying that carbon sequestration
might be nearly costless. Only few studies in the literature included possible secondary benefits and the
(b) Carbon ‘leakages’ occur when the effects of a carbon sequestration program leads to a countervailing
response beyond the boundary of the program. For example, if forestland is preserved from harvest and
conversion in one location, the unchanged demand for agricultural land and forest products could lead to
increased forest clearing and conversion in another region. Thus the effects of the preservation may be
partially or entirely undone by the ‘leakage’. Accounting for ‘leakage’ would increase the cost of
sequestration. Stavins (1999) is among the few studies, which address the ‘leakage’ issue. However,
‘leakage’ is not a problem concerned with carbon sequestration programs alone as similar concerns
surround the other GHG mitigation options as well. One way to check leakage could be by ensuring
payment to industrial and carbon forests for both their carbon and wood outputs.
(c) Impact on systems of public finance is not an issue that directly concerns the carbon sequestration cost
studies, but is of critical importance for effective implementation. In general, those instruments that
require revenue raising such as subsidies and contracts have a higher social cost than those that raise
revenue, such as auctioned marketable allowances and emissions taxes. Since carbon sequestration
programs are typically conceived through subsidies, the overall cost of sequestration would be more than
what the studies in the literature have reported so far.
All the unresolved issues listed above have a bearing on how the carbon sequestration program is
implemented and it is on this aspect the next section focuses.
2.0 Legal and Institutional Issues related to Carbon Sequestration
Key challenges inherent in the development of markets for carbon offset credits include:
• Measurement and verification of carbon storage, which includes the duration of time over which
carbon is stored, whether or not it is in addition to baseline storage, and the amount of .leakage. . i.e.,
carbon emitted elsewhere through displaced forest activities;
• Adjusting for uncertainty and for risks that carbon will be released sooner than the contractual
period, either intentionally or by accident or neglect, and assignment of liability when this occurs;
• Development of compatible regulatory frameworks at local, national and international levels
that include agreement on what activities are eligible for credits, and who will receive the credits;
• Establishment of institutional arrangements that reduce transaction costs; and
• Achievement of verifiable socio-economic as well as environmental benefits that strengthen
community livelihoods and support sustainable development objectives.
Carbon sequestration is a reversible process and the concerned legal system should clearly describe
who is responsible if the sequestered carbon is subsequently released and the basis for the credits
Liability and Issue of Permanence
To deal with lack of permanence of carbon credits a common approach has been either to acknowledge
the same, assess the environmental and economic benefits of limited-term sequestration, and allot credits
in proportion to the time period over which carbon is sequestered, or to provide reasonable assurance of
indefinite sequestration. The first alternative has led to what has been called the tonyear approach, in
which activities would accrue credits for each year that a ton of carbon is withheld from the atmosphere
and some quantity of ton-years would be equated with a permanent ton. For the second alternative, three
mechanisms have evolved for providing reasonable assurance of indefinite sequestration: a) provide
partial credits according to the perceived risk that they will be maintained for a specified time, b) link
temporary sequestration projects with obligations for later action to assure permanence of the emissions
reduction, and c) tax sequestration credits to finance research and development into emissions-saving
In a ton-year system, credit would be awarded for the number of tons of carbon held out of the
atmosphere for a given number of years and some equivalency factor would be defined to equate a
specific number of ‘ton-years’ with permanent sequestration. Several approaches have been suggested for
defining the equivalency factor, i.e. the number of ton-years that is to be equated with permanence (IPCC,
2000; Fearnside et al., 2000; Moura Costa and Wilson, 2000). Basically one would integrate over time the
number of tons sequestered and convert this to tons of carbon emissions offset by dividing the
equivalency factor, i.e. ton-years/f = permanent tons, where f is the equivalency factor. There is no unique
way to determine a conversion rate between ton-years and permanent tons and that the choice among a
number of justifiable possibilities is thus a policy decision. A new approach that avoids many of the
above mentioned problems is so called ‘rental’ approach suggested by Sedjo (2001). Just as a space can
be rented to provide for the temporary parking of a car, space could be rented for parking carbon.
An argument can be made that the liability should be borne by the tree owner (seller of sequestration
services) to ensure that incentives to continue the existence of the planted forest are maintained and thus
ensure that the carbon remains sequestered. However, with a long-term certificate, buyers of certificates
that were no longer valid would need to try to recover losses from the tree owners. Recovering
compensation could be difficult and costly and involve intercountry litigation. An alternative as
mentioned above would be for certificates to be valid for relatively short time periods, say, one year with
the renewal option. In short-term renewable credits it is easier to deal with compensation issue (in case of
either accidental or intentional destruction of the forest), particularly if payment is made after the carbon
has been sequestered for the required time period, i.e., at the end of the sequestration year rather than at
the beginning. The annual flow of income to the tree owners would generate the incentive to maintain the
trees and their carbon for another year. Under this system, the tree owner would be free to eliminate the
tree (for logging or land conversion) and release the carbon, but the cost to the owner would be the loss of
the annual income that would have been received for sequestering the carbon. Liability compensation,
however, need not be a problem for tree owners if the carbon payment is based on the carbon that has
already been sequestered for the previous period.
Institutional Issues - Some Existing Examples
The Kyoto Protocol of 1997 requires Annex I (industrialized) countries to reduce their emissions to 5
percent below 1990 levels by 2008-2012. These obligations can, in part, be met through three
mechanisms: joint implementation (JI), clean development mechanism (CDM), and international
emissions trading (IET). Under JI and CDM, emissions reductions can be done through Land Use, Land
Use Change and Forestry projects. CDM projects are restricted to afforestation and reforestation
activities, while JI projects may also include forest management activities. Thus, the Kyoto Protocol
provided the basis for generation of credits from sequestration programs but actual implementation is still
pending as the ‘rules of the game’ are still uncertain. Insights on institutional arrangements can be drawn
from available evidence from various experimental carbon sequestration programs.
A number of independent initiatives are springing up at national and international levels that use various
approaches. Although this diversity can lead to innovation and provide lessons, it may also reflect
conflicting interests that need to be reconciled. Ultimately, a global carbon market requires the support of
an institutional infrastructure that can increase investor confidence and reduce transaction costs in
international trading. This infrastructure may include national offices, regulatory agencies, and
establishment of trust funds, trading platforms such as exchanges, brokers, certifiers and insurers. For
example, establishing a national carbon registry can help to prevent double selling of carbon credits and
also provide transparency for prices that are critical to fair negotiations. Preventing leakage requires an
institutional capacity to enforce laws. This capacity also creates greater incentive to invest in sustainable
forestry practices such as Reduced Impact Logging that result in higher carbon retention. However, much
of the economic benefit from this is in higher future yields - provided that access to forests can be
controlled over the full rotation period.
Effective markets for carbon sequestration ultimately require benefits for forest communities, for without
communities’ cooperation on enforcement, these markets may be ineffective or expensive. Communities’
participation can lead to higher transaction costs, such projects will not always provide the lowest-cost
opportunity for offsetting carbon emissions, but this participation is consistent with the Kyoto Protocol.s
requirement that CDM projects promote sustainable development. The following table outlines a few
on-going programs on carbon sequestration.
Case study of pilot CDM project in Ecudator involving small-scale farmers
established 23000 hectare of pine, eucalyptus and indigenous species in a
deforested region with a combined aim of controlling erosion and
National forestry fund in Costa Rica to provide payments to protected areas
and private forest owners by contracting them for 20 years periods of
reforestation, sustainable forest management and forest prevention activities.
Certified Tradable Carbon Offsets (CTO’s) generated from the program are
sold to international investors and donors through a Joint Implementation
Office. Transactions costs are reduced through intermediatory organizations
which helps farmers with small plots to submit group applications.
Sells certified and Guaranteed Carbon Offsets also offers buyers from
Allows consumers to purchase carbon offsets with particular consumer
Joint business establishment of Toyota Motor Corporation, Mitsui Co. Ltd.,
and Nippon Paper Industries Co. Ltd., to plant and manage 5000 hectares of
eucalyptus forests. Toyota with major investment keeps the carbon credits
References:
Adams, D., R. Alig, B. McCarl, J. Callaway, and S. Winnett. 1999. .Minimum Cost Strategies for
Sequestering Carbon in Forests. Land Economics 75(3): 360-374.
Chomitz, K. M., 2000. .Evaluating Carbon Offsets from Forestry and Energy Projects: How do
they Compare?., World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2357, New York, 25 pp.
Fearnside, P. M., D. A. Lashof, and P. Moura-Costa, 2000. .Accounting for Time in Mitigating
Global Warming Through Land-Use Change and Forestry., Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, 2000.
Land Use, Land-Use Change, and Forestry: A Special Report of the IPCC, Cambridge University
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, 2001. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Kerr, S., A. Pfaff, and A. Sanchez. 2001. .The Dynamics of Deforestation and the Supply of
Carbon Sequestration: Illustrative Results from Costa Rica. In T. Panayoutou ed. Central America Project, Environment: Conservation and Competitiveness.
Harvard Institute for International Development.
Moura Costa, P. , and C. Wilson, 2000. .An Equivalence Factor Between CO
Avoided Emissions and Sequestration . Description and Applications in Forestry., Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change , 5: 51-60.
Newell, R. and R. Stavins. 2000. .Climate Change and Forest Sinks: Factors Affecting the Costs of
Carbon Sequestration. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 40(3): 211235.
Sedjo, R.A. 2001. .Forest Carbon Sequestration: Some Issues for Forest Investments., RFF Discussion Paper, 01-34, Resources for the Future, Washington, D.C.
Stavins, R. 1999. .The Costs of Carbon Sequestration: A Revealed-Preference Approach. American
derecho. O de como construirel objeto jurídicoL’auteur fonde sa thèse sur le fait qu’il n’est pas possible d’établir unedivision radicale entre le droit et la théorie qui étudie le droit commeobjet principal. Toutes les théories du droit, la dogmatique comme cellequi est fondée sur l’application des sciences sociales, participent, d’unemanière ou d’une autre, à la créa
Material Safety Data Sheet 1. IDENTIFICATION OF THE SUBSTANCE/MIXTURE AND THE COMPANY/UNDERTAKING Product Name Catalog No. Recommended Use Recommended Use antibiotic/antimycotic for cell culture, blocks the binding of tRNA to the 30S subunit Synonyms ACHROMYCIN HYDROCHLORIDE * ALA TET * AMYCIN, HYDROCHLORIDE*ARTOMYCIN * BRISTACYCLINE * CANCYCLINE-250 * CEFRACYCLINETABLETS